語系:
繁體中文
English
說明(常見問題)
回圖書館首頁
手機版館藏查詢
登入
回首頁
切換:
標籤
|
MARC模式
|
ISBD
The Impact of Economic Policies on H...
~
Zhong, Mingli.
FindBook
Google Book
Amazon
博客來
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior.
紀錄類型:
書目-電子資源 : Monograph/item
正題名/作者:
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior./
作者:
Zhong, Mingli.
出版者:
Ann Arbor : ProQuest Dissertations & Theses, : 2020,
面頁冊數:
114 p.
附註:
Source: Dissertations Abstracts International, Volume: 82-01, Section: A.
Contained By:
Dissertations Abstracts International82-01A.
標題:
Economics. -
電子資源:
https://pqdd.sinica.edu.tw/twdaoapp/servlet/advanced?query=27958919
ISBN:
9798641081380
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior.
Zhong, Mingli.
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior.
- Ann Arbor : ProQuest Dissertations & Theses, 2020 - 114 p.
Source: Dissertations Abstracts International, Volume: 82-01, Section: A.
Thesis (Ph.D.)--University of Pennsylvania, 2020.
This item is not available from ProQuest Dissertations & Theses.
Economic policies significantly influence household financial and labor supply decisions. In return, household responses to the policy change inform policy design. In this dissertation, I document how individuals respond to economic policies by adjusting their critical economic decisions: how much to save and how much to work. I also combine the welfare analysis of optimal economic policies that maximize individual welfare with empirical evidence on household and individual responses to economic policies. In the first chapter, I document the differential impacts of unemployment insurance on unemployment duration for older and younger workers. I find that older workers tend to receive longer periods of unemployment insurance than younger workers during economic downturns. This is partly because older workers have a harder time finding a job during economic downturns than younger workers. This age-specific difference is not salient in boom periods. I conclude that, since the purpose of unemployment insurance is to provide financial support for unemployed workers until they find a job, the optimal design of unemployment insurance needs to consider the differential job prospects across age groups. The policy implication is that it could be socially welfare improving to extend unemployment insurance for older workers so that they have a longer time period of time to find a new job. This could prevent older workers from leaving the workforce too early while they are still capable of working. Additionally, older workers might start claiming Social Security or withdrawing from their retirement accounts earlier than planned. Claiming Social Security at the earliest possible time could lead to a lower level of Social Security benefits for the rest of their life. Either withdrawing retirement savings too early or claiming a lower level of Social Security benefits potentially increases retirees' chances of late-life poverty and their reliance on means-tested social transfers. In the second chapter based on a working paper co-authored with John Chalmers, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Jonathan Reuter, we investigate the impact of a savings mandate imposed on private sector employers on expanding access to automatic enrollment retirement plans. Starting in 2017, the state of Oregon required that all private sector employers provide either an employer-sponsored retirement plan or enroll their employees into a state-sponsored retirement plan, called OregonSaves. We find about half of the workers who were automatically enrolled in OregonSaves chose to participate in the plan. The majority of participants stayed at the 5 percent default savings rate. In the third chapter, I investigate the impact of the default savings rate in automatic enrollment retirement plans on individual welfare. I propose a unified framework to analyze the welfare effects of the default savings rate and derive a formula for the optimal default savings rate that depends on observable statistics. Using individual-level administrative and survey data and an exogenous increase in the default savings rate from 5% to 6% in the OregonSaves program, I estimate key statistics in the optimal default formula and find that the optimal default savings rate to be 8%.
ISBN: 9798641081380Subjects--Topical Terms:
517137
Economics.
Subjects--Index Terms:
Automatic enrollment retirement plans
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior.
LDR
:04567nmm a2200385 4500
001
2280388
005
20210827095938.5
008
220723s2020 ||||||||||||||||| ||eng d
020
$a
9798641081380
035
$a
(MiAaPQ)AAI27958919
035
$a
AAI27958919
040
$a
MiAaPQ
$c
MiAaPQ
100
1
$a
Zhong, Mingli.
$3
3558902
245
1 4
$a
The Impact of Economic Policies on Household Financial and Labor Supply Behavior.
260
1
$a
Ann Arbor :
$b
ProQuest Dissertations & Theses,
$c
2020
300
$a
114 p.
500
$a
Source: Dissertations Abstracts International, Volume: 82-01, Section: A.
500
$a
Advisor: Mitchell, Olivia S.
502
$a
Thesis (Ph.D.)--University of Pennsylvania, 2020.
506
$a
This item is not available from ProQuest Dissertations & Theses.
506
$a
This item must not be sold to any third party vendors.
520
$a
Economic policies significantly influence household financial and labor supply decisions. In return, household responses to the policy change inform policy design. In this dissertation, I document how individuals respond to economic policies by adjusting their critical economic decisions: how much to save and how much to work. I also combine the welfare analysis of optimal economic policies that maximize individual welfare with empirical evidence on household and individual responses to economic policies. In the first chapter, I document the differential impacts of unemployment insurance on unemployment duration for older and younger workers. I find that older workers tend to receive longer periods of unemployment insurance than younger workers during economic downturns. This is partly because older workers have a harder time finding a job during economic downturns than younger workers. This age-specific difference is not salient in boom periods. I conclude that, since the purpose of unemployment insurance is to provide financial support for unemployed workers until they find a job, the optimal design of unemployment insurance needs to consider the differential job prospects across age groups. The policy implication is that it could be socially welfare improving to extend unemployment insurance for older workers so that they have a longer time period of time to find a new job. This could prevent older workers from leaving the workforce too early while they are still capable of working. Additionally, older workers might start claiming Social Security or withdrawing from their retirement accounts earlier than planned. Claiming Social Security at the earliest possible time could lead to a lower level of Social Security benefits for the rest of their life. Either withdrawing retirement savings too early or claiming a lower level of Social Security benefits potentially increases retirees' chances of late-life poverty and their reliance on means-tested social transfers. In the second chapter based on a working paper co-authored with John Chalmers, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Jonathan Reuter, we investigate the impact of a savings mandate imposed on private sector employers on expanding access to automatic enrollment retirement plans. Starting in 2017, the state of Oregon required that all private sector employers provide either an employer-sponsored retirement plan or enroll their employees into a state-sponsored retirement plan, called OregonSaves. We find about half of the workers who were automatically enrolled in OregonSaves chose to participate in the plan. The majority of participants stayed at the 5 percent default savings rate. In the third chapter, I investigate the impact of the default savings rate in automatic enrollment retirement plans on individual welfare. I propose a unified framework to analyze the welfare effects of the default savings rate and derive a formula for the optimal default savings rate that depends on observable statistics. Using individual-level administrative and survey data and an exogenous increase in the default savings rate from 5% to 6% in the OregonSaves program, I estimate key statistics in the optimal default formula and find that the optimal default savings rate to be 8%.
590
$a
School code: 0175.
650
4
$a
Economics.
$3
517137
650
4
$a
Public policy.
$3
532803
650
4
$a
Labor economics.
$3
642730
653
$a
Automatic enrollment retirement plans
653
$a
Behavioral public policy
653
$a
Optimal retirement saving policies
653
$a
OregonSaves
653
$a
Unemployment insurance
690
$a
0501
690
$a
0630
690
$a
0510
710
2
$a
University of Pennsylvania.
$b
Applied Economics.
$3
2093128
773
0
$t
Dissertations Abstracts International
$g
82-01A.
790
$a
0175
791
$a
Ph.D.
792
$a
2020
793
$a
English
856
4 0
$u
https://pqdd.sinica.edu.tw/twdaoapp/servlet/advanced?query=27958919
筆 0 讀者評論
館藏地:
全部
電子資源
出版年:
卷號:
館藏
1 筆 • 頁數 1 •
1
條碼號
典藏地名稱
館藏流通類別
資料類型
索書號
使用類型
借閱狀態
預約狀態
備註欄
附件
W9432121
電子資源
11.線上閱覽_V
電子書
EB
一般使用(Normal)
在架
0
1 筆 • 頁數 1 •
1
多媒體
評論
新增評論
分享你的心得
Export
取書館
處理中
...
變更密碼
登入